少点错误 2024年08月16日
Investigating the Chart of the Century: Why is food so expensive?
index_new5.html
../../../zaker_core/zaker_tpl_static/wap/tpl_guoji1.html

 

文章探讨了多种商品价格的变化,着重分析了食品和住房价格走势。技术进步使部分商品更易获得,但一些重要领域价格飙升。食品价格上涨幅度与住房相似,原因包括美国人外出就餐增加、餐厅成本受空间和人力影响、住房数据的构成、食品成分变化及运输成本等。

🥘食品价格走势:过去24年中,食品价格如住房价格一样上涨。美国人外出就餐增多,餐厅食物价格增长快于杂货价格,且‘食品在家’价格增长在2015年后才低于住房。同时,食品成分变化也影响价格。

🏠住房价格因素:BLS的‘住房’系列是‘住房’价格的综合指数,包括实际租金、水电费等。建筑生产力停滞和土地使用规定主要体现在租金上,其他部分掩盖了一些通货膨胀。

🚚运输成本影响:‘送货服务’价格通胀在所有类别中最高,运输和送货成本的增加导致了部分食品价格的上涨。

Published on August 16, 2024 1:21 PM GMT

You’ve probably seen this chart from Mark Perry at the American Enterprise Institute.

I’ve seen this chart dozens of times and have always enjoyed how many different and important stories it can tell.

There is a story of the incredible abundance offered by technological growth and globalization. Compared to average hourly wages, cars, furniture, clothing, internet access, software, toys, and TVs have become far more accessible than they were 20 years ago. Flatscreens and Fiats that were once luxuries are now commodities.

There is also a story of sclerosis and stagnation. Sure, lots of frivolous consumer goods have gotten cheaper but healthcare, housing, childcare, and education, all the important stuff, has exploded in price. Part of this is “cost disease” where the high productivity of labor in advancing industries like software, raises the cost of labor in slower productivity growth industries like healthcare. Another part is surely the near-universal “restrict supply and subsidize demand” strategy that governments undertake when regulating an industry. Zoning laws + Prop 13 in housing, occupational licensing and the FDA + Medicare in healthcare, and free student debt + all of the above for higher ed.

One story from this graph I’ve never heard and only recently noticed is that “Food and Beverages” has inflated just as much as Housing in this graph. This is extremely counterintuitive. Food is a globally traded and mass produced commodity while housing is tied to inelastic land supply in desirable locations. Farming, grocery, and restaurants are competitive and relatively lightly regulated markets while the housing is highly regulated, subsidized, and distorted. Construction productivity is worse than stagnant while agricultural productivity has been ascendent for the past 300 years and even retail productivity is 8x higher than it was in 1950. Construction is also more labor intensive than farming or staffing the grocery.

Source

Yet food prices have risen just as much as housing prices over the past 24 years. What explains this?

One trend is that Americans are eating out more. The “Food and Beverages” series from the BLS includes both “Food At Home” and “Food Away From Home.” In 2023, eating out was a larger portion of the average household’s budget than food at home for the first time, but they have been converging for more than 50 years.

Restaurant food prices have increased faster than grocery prices. This makes sense, as a much larger portion of a restaurant’s costs are location and labor, both of which are affected by tight supply constraints on urban floor space. This isn’t enough to satisfy my surprise at the similarity in price growth though. Even if we just look at “food at home” price growth, it only really sinks below housing after 2015. Beverages at home/away from home follow a more divergent version of the same pattern, but are a much smaller part of the weighted average that makes up the aggregate index.

The BLS series for “Housing” is also an aggregate index of “Shelter” prices, which is the actual rent (or Owner Rent Equivalent), and other expenses like utilities, moving, and repairs. Stagnant construction productivity and land use regulation will show up mostly in rents so these other pieces of the series are masking a bit of the inflation.

There is also changing composition within the “Food at home” category. Americans eat more fats and oils, more sugars and sweets, more grains, and more red meat; all four items that grew the most in price since 2003.

There’s also a flipside to food and beverage’s easy tradability: they’re closer to the same price everywhere. House prices per square foot, by contrast, differ by more than $1000 just across the boroughs of New York City. Over the period tracked by this index there has been massive migration between the most expensive housing states and the cheapest ones. This means the average housing price tracked by BLS gets weighted more towards the Austin housing market as the San Francisco and NYC markets keep rising.

Mike Konczal has a nice breakdown of the BLS indices behind the AEI graph where he shows, among other things, that “Delivery Services” had the highest price inflation of any category over the period, beating out “Hospital Services” by about 10 percentage points. So some of the inflation is due to this cost of trucking and delivery.

These considerations widen the gap between food prices and housing prices, but not nearly as much as the gap between housing and cars or clothing. I’m still pretty surprised by the similarity and I’m not sure why food tracks housing so much more closely than clothing, which seems like a much closer match in terms of supply chain and market structure.



Discuss

Fish AI Reader

Fish AI Reader

AI辅助创作,多种专业模板,深度分析,高质量内容生成。从观点提取到深度思考,FishAI为您提供全方位的创作支持。新版本引入自定义参数,让您的创作更加个性化和精准。

FishAI

FishAI

鱼阅,AI 时代的下一个智能信息助手,助你摆脱信息焦虑

联系邮箱 441953276@qq.com

相关标签

食品价格 住房价格 价格通胀 成本因素
相关文章