少点错误 2024年09月05日
UBI isn’t designed for technological unemployment
index_new5.html
../../../zaker_core/zaker_tpl_static/wap/tpl_guoji1.html

 

本文探讨了通用基本收入(UBI)作为应对大规模科技失业的保险方案的可行性,并以瑞士全民基本收入公投为例,分析了UBI在应对科技失业方面的成本和可持续性问题。作者认为,UBI在应对科技失业方面存在成本高昂且缺乏可持续性的问题,并建议以更灵活的政策工具来应对未来的科技失业挑战。

🇨🇭 UBI应对科技失业成本高昂:在科技失业的情况下,UBI需要完全替代劳动收入,而保证最低收入(GMI)则可以更经济地应对科技失业,其成本会随着失业率上升而逐渐接近UBI。 UBI和GMI都是旨在提供经济保障的社会福利方案,但二者在实施机制和成本方面存在差异。UBI通常以定期现金支付的形式,对所有公民发放,而GMI则设定一个最低收入标准,对于收入低于标准的人进行补贴。 在劳动经济中,GMI的实施成本远低于相同金额的UBI,因为GMI只对收入低于标准的人提供补贴,而UBI则对所有人发放。然而,在科技失业的情况下,GMI的成本会随着失业率上升而迅速增加,因为更多的人将需要接受补贴。最终,GMI的成本会逐渐接近UBI。 在科技失业的情况下,UBI需要完全替代劳动收入,而GMI则可以更经济地应对科技失业。

💰 UBI的资金来源问题:UBI的资金来源主要依靠税收,而科技失业会导致劳动收入减少,进而导致税收减少,难以维持UBI的长期运行。 UBI的资金来源主要依靠税收,其中大部分来自劳动收入税。当科技失业导致劳动收入减少时,税收也会随之减少,进而导致UBI资金不足。 例如,瑞士全民基本收入公投中,政府预测UBI需要约2080亿瑞士法郎的年度预算,其中约1280亿瑞士法郎来自劳动收入税。如果科技失业导致劳动收入大幅减少,那么UBI将面临巨大的资金缺口。 因此,UBI在应对科技失业方面存在资金来源的风险。

🤖 科技失业的程度尚不确定:目前尚不清楚科技发展会对就业市场造成多大的影响,因此过早实施UBI可能造成资源浪费。 科技发展对就业市场的影响尚不确定。一些人认为科技发展会带来大规模的失业,而另一些人则认为科技发展会创造新的就业机会。目前尚无确凿证据证明科技发展会导致大规模的失业。 过早实施UBI可能会导致资源浪费。如果科技发展并没有导致大规模的失业,那么UBI的实施将造成巨大的财政负担。 因此,在实施UBI之前,需要谨慎评估科技发展对就业市场的影响,并根据具体情况进行调整。

Published on September 5, 2024 3:39 PM GMT

A universal basic income (UBI) is often presented as a public insurance against large-scale and potentially permanent technological unemployment. Many Silicon Valley leaders that believe in and work on the transformative economic potential of artificial general intelligence (AGI) have also voiced their support for UBI:

We should welcome the public discussion on UBI as well as the various small-scale trials of it, particularly in anticipation of a machine economy. However, in relative terms, there is too much focus on plans to publicly distribute money to everyone. Spending money is the easy part. The hard part is designing income streams that scale in lockstep with the machine economy and can finance a rising demand for social security.

My argument is not that UBI cannot or should not be part of the policy tools to address long-term technological unemployment. My argument is that a UBI to address long-term technological unemployment is more expensive than current UBI proposals and that it is not a sustainable solution to finance an insurance against widespread loss of labor income by taxing labor income:

1. UBI for technological unemployment is expensive

1.1 A guaranteed minimum income is cheaper than UBI, but would approach the cost of UBI in a post-labor economy

In the public discourse, the terms UBI and guaranteed minimum income are often used interchangeably. However, they denote different concepts and many famous “UBI proposals” and “UBI trials” are actually guaranteed minimum income proposals and trials. The main reason for this is that guaranteed minimum income is much cheaper to implement than a UBI. However, in a scenario of large-scale unemployment the costs of guaranteed minimum income would rise rapidly and approach the cost of a UBI.

Universal basic income

A UBI is commonly defined as having the following characteristics:

In a UBI everyone actually receives a transfer payment. The idea is that making the payments universal increases buy-in for the program and reduces the stigma of needs-based benefits (“like a school uniform”).

Visualisation of a UBI in a labor economy with income on y-axis, market income in blue, UBI in red.

A good example of a UBI proposal is the “Freedom Dividend”, the signature policy proposal of the 2020 Democratic primary candidate Andrew Yang. The proposal would give every US-citizen over the age of 18 1’000 USD per month per person. 

Guaranteed minimum income

A guaranteed minimum income or negative income tax is the idea that the state will ensure that everyone reaches a minimum monthly or yearly income. If you don’t reach it, the state will pay the difference, otherwise you will not get anything. So, while the cash payments do not require any active action, payments are withdrawn as labor income rises.[1]

Visualisation of a guaranteed minimum income in a labor economy with income on y-axis, market income in blue, and guaranteed minimum income in red.

Good examples of guaranteed minimum income proposals are those put forward in the United States in the 1960s and 1970s by Milton Friedman, Richard Nixon, and George McGovern

In a labor economy, a guaranteed minimum income is a lot cheaper to implement than a universal basic income of the same amount. However, this also means that the costs of a guaranteed minimum income program would rise rapidly in the case of technological mass unemployment as the number of beneficiaries expands. In contrast, the cost of a UBI remains the same regardless of the number of unemployed and underemployed.

Visualisation of how a guaranteed minimum income in a full automation economy might look like with income on y-axis, capital income in blue, and guaranteed minimum income in red.

1.2 A public spending-neutral UBI is not enough in a post-labor economy

Supporters of UBI like to point out that a remarkably heterogeneous coalition of thinkers including technologists, libertarians, and socialists support the idea of a UBI. However, as always, the devil lies in the details.

Thinkers on the left, such as Philippe Van Parijs & Yannick Vanderborght (2017), generally look at a relatively generous UBI as a foundation to build stronger and much more expansive welfare states. In contrast, libertarian thinkers, such as Charles Murray (2006), are more interested in a public spending-neutral UBI. In other words a UBI that is entirely financed by replacing existing welfare spending. 

a) A public spending-neutral UBI would reduce income for some low income households

A spending-neutral UBI reform financed by cutting a large fraction of existing social security programs would increase the amount of beneficiaries that receive a share of social security spending (everyone) at the expense of lower spending per beneficiary. Meaning, it would generate more winners than losers among the population. However, the average loser loses more than the average winners gains. In most countries the current allocation of social assistance programs is more effective in reducing poverty than a spending-neutral UBI reform.[2]

Under spending-neutrality the UBI would have to be set considerably below national poverty lines. According to the OECD, a budget-neutral UBI would amount to €158 per month per adult in Italy, £230 in the United Kingdom, €456 in France, and €527 in Finland.

b) A UBI large enough to maintain or increase transfers to all low-income households would be very expensive 

Financing a UBI at 100 per cent of the national poverty line for adults and 50 per cent to children up to 15 years old, would cost between 20 and 30 per cent of GDP in middle income and high income countries and 50 per cent or more in low income countries (graph below). 

Source: Isabel Ortiz et al. (2018). Universal Basic Income proposals in light of ILO standards: Key issues and global costing. ilo.org p. 15

c) In a post-labor economy we would optimally have a universal high income

A universal basic income should be enough to live on, but just barely. The exact amount differs based on regional income and purchasing power levels. However, most proposals are set below and at best at the local poverty line. The idea is that you have peace of mind if you need to leave an abusive partner, a toxic job, look after a child or try to pursue self-employment. However, you should still be incentivized to seek employment again.

In contrast, if the premise is a persistent problem of technological employment that renders a significant share of the population “unemployable” then a basic income is not exactly utopia. It would ensure that no one starves but it would essentially create a permanent underclass. Hence, some, such as Elon Musk, hope that a growing machine economy will enable a “universal high income”, where humans can comfortably live indefinitely without having to work.

Today, most “UBI” trials use some mechanism to select participants with low income and are closer to a guaranteed minimum income. They are tested as an alternative to other forms of social security or as a supplemental income to low-income households. Hence, they may find that people receiving a UBI have improved well-being. Who wants to run the experiment measuring the well-being effects of replacing the salary of programmers with a 1’000 USD a month UBI?

2. Financing a UBI by taxing labor is not “post-labor proof”

Let’s look at the Swiss popular initiative “For an unconditional basic income”. The initiators have proposed[3] that all permanent resident adults should receive 2’500 CHF (ca. 2950 USD) per month and all children and young people 625 CHF (ca. 730 USD) per month. These numbers were also used in an accompanying volume of essays published by supporters of the initiative and the government has used these numbers as the basis for official calculations presented in the official voting material. 

Specifically, the government calculated that the proposed universal basic income would cost about 208 billion CHF annually (ca. 30% of GDP) to cover 6.5 million adults and around 1.5 million children and young people.[4] In discussions with the initiators, the government calculated that the basic income would replace many existing social security benefits, the corresponding savings could finance around 55 billion. Still, social security spending would have to be nearly quadrupled and an additional 153 billion would be required. Around 128 billion CHF of this could be covered by deducting 2’500 CHF from every earned income, or the entire income for incomes below 2’500 CHF.[5] The remaining gap of 25 billion CHF or so would have to be financed by significant savings or tax increases. For example, the VAT could be doubled from 8 to 16 per cent. 

So, what’s the issue?

2.1 We don’t know how soon we may run out jobs

A further expansion of the welfare state without significant automation may be premature. Many advanced economies face rapidly ageing societies with worsening dependency ratios and historically high levels of public debt.

We also know that there have been previous waves of automation anxiety that ultimately turned out to be false alarms. Supporters of the initiative held a “robots for UBI” protest and stressed the progress of automation: “Robots are doing more and more work. It is now our task to shape society in such a way that everyone has a dignified life thanks to the digital revolution: More meaningful and self-determined activities are possible.”[6] And yet, here we are another 7 years later: We still haven’t even managed to automate trains and many Western economies have labor and skills shortages. Given this context, we may want to scale a UBI incrementally, in lockstep with the expansion of the AI economy.

2.2 Most financing of the Swiss UBI would fall away in a post-labor scenario

Let’s make an extremized thought experiment and assume that AI will replace all human jobs within the next 10 years. Nearly two-thirds of the foreseen funding for the UBI came from labor income tax. If labor becomes obsolete there is suddenly a 128 billion CHF funding gap. On top of that, labor income taxes also form the backbone of the general government budget of Switzerland and most other developed nations. Across the member states of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), about 50% of all tax revenues in 2023 came from individual income taxes and social security contributions.

In short, as the Genevan law professor Xavier Oberson argued: “Should mass workplaces for humans disappear in the future, from a tax perspective a double negative effect could occur. On the one hand, significant tax and social security revenues would be lost, while on the other hand, the need would increase for additional state revenue to support the growing number of unemployed human workers.” 

Solutions

What is needed to address both the timing uncertainty and the long-term financing issue of UBI with regards to the prospect of technological unemployment is a financing mechanism that scales with the growth of the machine economy. I will explore the strengths and weaknesses of some of the more popular suggestions to address this in future posts.

  1. ^

    This can be based on monthly or annual income checks and with corresponding phaseout provisions. In the extreme case, this can mean that participants have up to 100% marginal tax rate for earning additional income through labor until they reach the minimum income. However, something like 50% phase-out is more common. As Scott Santens has explained, a 100% marginal tax rate reduces willingness to work and hence this is not the best design in the current system.

  2. ^

    Ugo Gentilini, Margaret Grosh, Jamele Rigolini, & Ruslan Yemtsov. (2020). Universal Basic Income: A Guide to Navigating Concepts, Evidence, and Practices. worldbank.org p. 133

  3. ^

    Strictly speaking the text on which the Swiss voted did not specify how high the UBI would be, how it would be financed and who exactly exactly would be entitled to it. In some sense, one can view this as strategic ambiguity to get buy-in from more socialist and more libertarian UBI supporters. 

  4. ^
  5. ^

    This financing mechanism means that even though the Swiss proposal is a UBI in which everyone receives an actual transfer, it would have had the characteristics of a guaranteed minimum income with a 100% marginal tax rate on labor income from 0 to 2’500 CHF.

  6. ^


Discuss

Fish AI Reader

Fish AI Reader

AI辅助创作,多种专业模板,深度分析,高质量内容生成。从观点提取到深度思考,FishAI为您提供全方位的创作支持。新版本引入自定义参数,让您的创作更加个性化和精准。

FishAI

FishAI

鱼阅,AI 时代的下一个智能信息助手,助你摆脱信息焦虑

联系邮箱 441953276@qq.com

相关标签

通用基本收入 科技失业 瑞士 公投 经济
相关文章