Astral Codex Ten Podcast feed 2024年07月17日
List of Passages I Highlighted in My Copy of Capital in the Twenty-First Century
index_new5.html
../../../zaker_core/zaker_tpl_static/wap/tpl_guoji1.html

 

本文探讨了李嘉图和马克思两位经济学家对资本主义的分析,他们都基于对资本主义内部逻辑矛盾的分析,并提出了各自的理论。李嘉图认为,随着人口和产出的增长,土地变得越来越稀缺,导致地租不断上升,最终会扰乱社会平衡。马克思则进一步发展了李嘉图的理论,他认为资本的积累会无限地集中在少数人手中,最终导致资本主义的崩溃。

📈 **李嘉图的土地租金理论**:李嘉图认为,随着人口和产出的增长,土地变得越来越稀缺,导致地租不断上升。他认为,土地租金的上升会侵蚀其他阶层的收入,最终会导致社会不稳定。为了解决这个问题,他主张对地租征收累进税。 虽然李嘉图的预测没有完全实现,但他对土地租金的分析揭示了资本主义制度中存在的潜在矛盾。他认为,土地的稀缺性会限制经济增长,并导致财富分配不均。 李嘉图的理论对后来的经济学家产生了深远的影响,尤其是马克思。马克思将李嘉图的土地租金理论扩展到资本积累的分析,并认为资本的无限积累最终会导致资本主义的崩溃。

📊 **马克思的资本积累理论**:马克思继承了李嘉图的思想,并将其应用于工业资本的分析。他认为,资本的积累会无限地集中在少数人手中,最终导致资本主义的崩溃。 马克思认为,资本主义制度的内在矛盾在于,资本家为了追求利润最大化,会不断地压榨工人,导致工人阶级贫困化。同时,资本的积累会集中在少数人手中,导致社会财富分配不均。 马克思预测,资本主义最终会走向灭亡,因为资本的积累会不断地加剧社会矛盾,最终导致工人阶级革命。

📋 **历史的教训**:李嘉图和马克思的理论都基于对资本主义制度的分析,并提出了各自的预测。虽然他们的预测没有完全实现,但他们的理论揭示了资本主义制度中存在的潜在矛盾。 他们的理论提醒我们,资本主义制度并非完美无缺,它存在着许多问题,需要我们不断地反思和改进。我们需要关注社会公平,并努力构建一个更加公正和可持续发展的社会。

📌 **科技进步和社会变革**:值得注意的是,李嘉图和马克思都生活在工业革命初期,他们无法预料到科技进步对经济和社会的影响。 科技进步不仅提高了生产效率,也创造了新的产业和就业机会。同时,科技进步也改变了人们的生活方式和价值观,促进了社会变革。 因此,在分析资本主义制度时,我们需要考虑科技进步和社会变革的影响。

📍 **理性主义的局限性**:李嘉图和马克思都是理性主义者,他们试图用逻辑推理来解释社会现象。然而,社会是一个复杂的系统,充满了随机性和不确定性。 理性主义者往往忽视了人类情感、文化和制度等因素对社会的影响。因此,他们的理论往往存在局限性,无法完全解释社会现象。 我们需要认识到理性主义的局限性,并采用更全面的视角来分析社会问题。

[Original review is here. Don’t worry, people who had interesting comments on the review – I’ll try to get a comments highlights thread up eventually.]

For Ricardo, who published his Principles of Political Economy and Taxation in 1817, the chief concern was the long-term evolution of land prices and land rents. Like Malthus, he had virtually no genuine statistics at his disposal. He nevertheless had intimate knowledge of the capitalism of his time. Born into a family of Jewish financiers with Portuguese roots, he also seems to have had fewer political prejudices than Malthus, Young, or Smith. He was influenced by the Malthusian model but pushed the argument farther. He was above all interested in the following logical paradox. Once both population and output begin to grow steadily, land tends to become increasingly scarce relative to other goods. The law of supply and demand then implies that the price of land will rise continuously, as will the rents paid to landlords. The landlords will therefore claim a growing share of national income, as the share available to the rest of the population decreases, thus upsetting the social equilibrium. For Ricardo, the only logically and politically acceptable answer was to impose a steadily increasing tax on land rents.

This somber prediction proved wrong: land rents did remain high for an extended period, but in the end the value of farm land inexorably declined relative to other forms of wealth as the share of agriculture in national income decreased. Writing in the 1810s, Ricardo had no way of anticipating the importance of technological progress or industrial growth in the years ahead. Like Malthus and Young, he could not imagine that humankind would ever be totally freed from the alimentary imperative.

One underappreciated feature of Piketty is his engaging presentation of economic history. A constant feature of the theorists he discusses is that they are all brilliant thinkers, they all follow the trends of their time to their obvious conclusions in ways deeper and more insightful than their contemporaries – and they all miss complicated paradigm shifts that make the trends obsolete and totally ruin their theories. Rationalists take note.

Like Ricardo, Marx based his work on an analysis of the internal logical contradictions of the capitalist system. He therefore sought to distinguish himself from both bourgeois economists (who saw the market as a self-regulated system, that is, a system capable of achieving equilibrium on its own without major deviations, in accordance with Adam Smith’s image of “the invisible hand” and Jean-Baptiste Say’s “law” that production creates its own demand), and utopian socialists and Proudhonians, who in Marx’s view were content to denounce the misery of the working class without proposing a truly scientific analysis of the economic processes responsible for it.7 In short, Marx took the Ricardian model of the price of capital and the principle of scarcity as the basis of a more thorough analysis of the dynamics of capitalism in a world where capital was primarily industrial (machinery, plants, etc.) rather than landed property, so that in principle there was no limit to the amount of capital that could be accumulated. In fact, his principal conclusion was what one might call the “principle of infinite accumulation,” that is, the inexorable tendency for capital to accumulate and become concentrated in ever fewer hands, with no natural limit to the process. This is the basis of Marx’s prediction of an apocalyptic end to capitalism: either the rate of return on capital would steadily diminish (thereby killing the engine of accumulation and leading to violent conflict among capitalists), or capital’s share of national income would increase indefinitely (which sooner or later would unite the workers in revolt). In either case, no stable socioeconomic or political equilibrium was possible.

Fish AI Reader

Fish AI Reader

AI辅助创作,多种专业模板,深度分析,高质量内容生成。从观点提取到深度思考,FishAI为您提供全方位的创作支持。新版本引入自定义参数,让您的创作更加个性化和精准。

FishAI

FishAI

鱼阅,AI 时代的下一个智能信息助手,助你摆脱信息焦虑

联系邮箱 441953276@qq.com

相关标签

李嘉图 马克思 资本主义 经济学 社会学
相关文章